Boletín de Estudios Económicos

ISSN 0006-6249 (Print)

ISSN 2951-6722 (Online)

DOI: https://doi.org/10.18543/bee

Vol. LXXIX Diciembre / December 2024 Núm. / No. 235

DOI: https://doi.org/10.18543/bee782342023

Construyendo futuros competitivos sostenibles a través de la investigación transformadora / Building sustainable competitiveness futures through transformative research

Artículos

TERRITORIAL COMPETITIVENESS FOR THE INTERESTS OF PUBLICS

COMPETITIVIDAD TERRITORIAL EN INTERÉS DE LOS PÚBLICOS

Silvia Sacchetti [*]

University of Trento, Italy

Roger Sugden [**]

University of British Columbia, Canada

doi: https://doi.org/10.18543/bee.2944

Recibido: 28 de diciembre de 2023
Aceptado: 14 de marzo de 2024
Publicado en línea: febrero de 2025

ABSTRACT

Competitiveness refers to a territory successfully satisfying its aims and objectives. In both research and practice, aims and objectives are usually specified in terms of compatibility with market success (e.g., performance in international trade) and/or the success of hierarchies (e.g., performance of large corporations). We suggest a different paradigm, focused on compatibility with the interests of publics, i.e., groups of people who share concerns about what is happening in an economy. Achieving this would require forums where people could freely inquire about the territory. They could then recognise their concerns about choice of the territory’s aims and objectives, and might identify when they share concerns, i.e., when they constitute a public. The forums would enable people to learn and experience, observe, discuss, share understanding and ideas, express their voice, and listen to others. Despite university governance and epistemic governance tending to crowd-out space for activities centred on publics, one way that researchers can help to create forums is by cooperating with citizens, community groups, policy-makers, and diaspora. Together, they might reframe the nature and purpose of territorial competitiveness, making it for the interests of publics.

Keywords: Competitiveness, Organisation of production, Public interest, University researchers.

RESUMEN

La competitividad se refiere al éxito de un territorio en la consecución de sus metas y objetivos. Tanto en la investigación como en la práctica, las metas y los objetivos suelen especificarse en términos de éxito del mercado (por ejemplo, los resultados en el comercio internacional) y/o el éxito de las jerarquías (por ejemplo, los resultados de las grandes empresas). Proponemos un paradigma diferente, centrado en la compatibilidad con los intereses de los públicos, es decir, los grupos de personas que comparten inquietudes acerca de lo que sucede en una economía. Para lograrlo se necesitarían foros en los que la gente pudiera informarse libremente sobre el territorio. Así podrían reconocer sus inquietudes sobre la elección de los fines y objetivos del territorio, y podrían identificar cuándo se comparten inquietudes, es decir, cuando constituyen un público. Los foros permitirían a las personas observar, debatir, compartir conocimientos e ideas, expresar su voz y escuchar a los demás. A pesar de que la gobernanza universitaria y epistémica tiende a excluir el espacio para las actividades centradas en los públicos, una forma en que los investigadores pueden ayudar a crear foros es a través de la cooperación con ciudadanos, grupos comunitarios, responsables políticos y la diáspora. Juntos, podrían replantear la naturaleza y el propósito de la competitividad territorial, poniéndola al servicio de los intereses de los públicos.

Palabras clave: Competitividad, Organización de la producción, Interés público, Investigación universitaria.

Summary: 1. Introduction: focus and scope.

1.  Introduction: focus and scope

This essay suggests a framework for addressing the nature and purpose of territorial competitiveness. To do so, we draw on studies of the organisation of production, and Deweyan analysis of the interests of publics, a neglected topic in competitiveness discussions.

Competitiveness refers to a territory successfully satisfying its aims and objectives, but the specification of those aims and objectives is contestable. Typically, they are defined in terms of market success (e.g., in international trade, or in service industries such as tourism and higher education) and/or the success of hierarchies (e.g., corporations). In contrast, we suggest a focus on the interests of publics, i.e., groups of people who share concerns about what is happening in an economy.

Being for the interests of publics would align with being inclusive, other-regarding, and mutually supportive. It would also entail messy and complex processes that enable publics to identify themselves and their interests; and to translate those interests into actions and policies. Territories seeking competitiveness for publics would need to take on the challenge of developing those processes.

The essay shows how researchers might use our suggested framework as a basis for their action, so that they can enhance processes of understanding and action in territorial competitiveness policy in practice. We advocate purposeful cooperation with community groups, citizens and policy-makers to develop stimulating and challenging spaces that enable publics to identify themselves, voice their interests, and influence future success.

2.  Context: the organisation of production

Following seminal research by Ronald Coase and Oliver Williamson that developed transaction cost theory, markets and hierarchies have long been seen as alternative means of organising production (Coase, 1937; Williamson, 1975). The idea is that production can be imagined as a series of transactions, each of which could in theory either be carried out using an arm’s length trade on an open market, or within a hierarchy characterised by centralised direction and control, or indeed a mix of the two. For instance, in England in the Industrial Revolution, the market-based putting-out system, in which the organiser of production contracted with people to spin wool in their own homes, was replaced by the hierarchical factory, where people came to work under direct supervision and for set hours (Marglin, 1974). A reverse tendency was seen in the 1990s, when a wave of marketisation across western countries was associated with private corporations and public bodies contracting on the market for the provision of services that were previously delivered within the organisation, such as office cleaning, and catering facilities for employees and customers. More generally, the norm for any particular territory is to observe both markets and hierarchies being used in the organisation of production. Transaction cost theory argues that the choice between these possibilities would be made on cost grounds – efficiency requires the cheaper transaction to prevail, with efficiency being mostly understood in terms of benefit to investors. Impacts on other groups of people are largely ignored (Sacchetti & Borzaga, 2021).

In contrast, more recent literature recognises that the organisation of production can be conceived, not necessarily with reference to markets and hierarchies, but in terms of compatibility with the interests of publics. See Branston et al. (200a6) on the organisation of large corporations; Sacchetti and Sugden (2009a) and Sacchetti et al. (2009) on organisation more generally; Sacchetti (2015) on governance, and preferences about including or excluding the interests of publics; Branston et al. (2016) on financial and energy sectors; and Conyon et al. (2022) for an appreciation of a segment of this literature in the context of monopoly capitalism analysis.

This literature focuses on governance, and the idea that actions have consequences, both for those directly engaged in the action, and for others. The economic governance of an organisation refers to its control, specifically to strategic decisions about its broad direction; to how strategic decisions are made, by whom, on what basis, for whose benefit. The argument is that strategic decisions impact not only the decision-makers (e.g., in large corporations, the senior managers) but also others (e.g., investors, employees, and consumers) (Branston et al., 2006a). That is where publics enter the analysis.

For John Dewey, a public is a group of people who share a concern for the “serious and enduring consequences” of an act that they are not directly engaged in (e.g., groups of investors, employees or consumers concerned about the strategic decisions of a corporation) (Dewey, 1927). Dewey also argued that, whenever there is an act, there can be multiple publics, each with its shared concerns. For example, employees might form a group sharing interest in a corporation’s strategic decision to cut prices and increase employment, as might consumers.

When those who govern an organisation make a choice, they express a specific preference, or value, towards including or excluding the interests of publics (Sacchetti, 2015). It follows that the organisation of production can be understood as the outcome of the values of decision-makers; and it can be conceived – as well as mapped – in terms of the outcome’s compatibility with the interests of publics, in addition to the use of markets and hierarchies. This conception is depicted in Figure 1.

The points of the triangle in Figure 1 represent three ideal-types in which, respectively, production is organised entirely through markets, or hierarchies, or in accord with the interests of publics. An area within the triangle represents production in practice. Varieties of market system map to an area close to the markets-hierarchies spectrum, far from compatibility with the interests of publics. The distance between such an area and the point of the triangle representing compatibility with the interests of publics is a measure of the foregone public value generated by the use of the market or hierarchy in an exclusive way, i.e., for restricted, private interests. It is the system’s degree of negative external effects, or its collective inefficiencies. Viewed from the opposite perspective, the distance represents the scope for improvement, where alternative modes of production can be applied to produce net public value.[1]

Figure 1

Markets, hierarchies, publics, and the organisation of production

3.  What is territorial competitiveness for?

We suggest that Figure 1 depicts not only the organisation of production but also a novel starting-point for thinking about territorial competitiveness. That is because the usual focus on markets and hierarchies in economic analysis of the organisation of production is paralleled by a concern with markets and hierarchies in much of the literature on competitiveness. Yet if the organisation of production concerns the interests of publics, the same can be said for territorial competitiveness.

Competitiveness is a term that emerged in the 1990s to denote particular approaches to aspects of the socio-economic development of territories. It is a relational concept about the perceived success of a territory.

Typically, a territory is seen to be competitive with respect to other territories. That is often taken to mean that territories are in competition with each other, but that is not strictly the case; competitiveness only implies comparison across territories. See Branston et al. (2006b) on the health sector, and Sacchetti et al. (2009) more generally. In principle, a territory could be seen as competitive not only compared to another territory but also compared to an ideal-type, or to itself. For example, over time a territory might increase its competitiveness by being more successful in what it does than previously.

Whilst there is consensus in published research that competitiveness refers to a territory successfully satisfying its aims and objectives, there is contestability about the specification of those aims and objectives, and how to achieve them. Discourse has tended to favour “rather narrow, private sector originated agendas”, not broader concerns (Bristow, 2005). Those agendas have often resulted in a market criterion being used – e.g., that territories aim for success in free international trade, or in service industries such as tourism, and higher education. Other times, success has been equated with the performance of privately controlled hierarchical organisations, e.g., what is good for the large corporation is good for the territory.

Analogy to the markets, hierarchies, publics triangle in Figure 1 suggests another possibility: that territorial competitiveness be conceived in terms of compatibility with the interests of publics. The implication of this possibility for the purpose of competitiveness is depicted in Figure 2.[2]

Figure 2

The purpose of territorial competitiveness

4.  What does compatibility with the interests of publics entail?

Policy-makers often assert that they know the interests of publics – at least, politicians often seem to make that claim – but actually, identifying the interests of publics is an extremely messy process. A particular challenge is that publics are what John Dewey called “amorphous and unarticulated” (Dewey, 1927). A group of people may not realise that they share an interest in a territory’s economic aims. Even if they do, they may find it problematic to articulate and identify that interest. There is also the complication of multiple, overlapping groups being interested in a territory’s aims – indeed, the set of publics and their interests will constantly emerge and change as people share, learn, and experience with each other, and as the territory itself changes.

Following Dewey, a process for untangling such complexity ideally entails the development of forums for democratic deliberation across all aspects of a territory’s economy and society, and involving all people interested in its competitiveness. The forums need to focus on people identifying where they share interests in the aims and objectives of the territory, i.e., on publics identifying themselves and their interests; and on the translation of those interests into actions and policies for a territory to achieve success.

Democratic deliberation implies both “freedom of social inquiry and of distribution of its conclusions”, and ‘‘improvement of the methods and conditions of debate, discussion and persuasion” (Dewey, 1927). A corollary is that people embrace the corresponding supporting values and define shared rules, such as (Sacchetti & Sugden, 2009a):

Reject attempts to control processes and outcomes.

Require inclusion of all people on equal terms.

Be other-regarding, not only self-regarding.

Be mutually supportive through reciprocity.

Embrace informed participation and continuous learning.

Extant western market economies typically reject a deliberative culture, instead favouring the assignment and use of property rights to define who controls resources and who is excluded, on the basis of self-interest. For instance, it is common for university students to pay rent for a room in the private market – student access to housing is typically in the hands of private landlords. For some students, this cost is a barrier to accessing education. For others, those who can afford to rent in the private sector, the consequence can be nonetheless impoverishing for their families. Yet the values of western market economies leave landlords free to speculate and accumulate resources, notwithstanding the interests of students and their families. The widespread use of short-term letting through digital platforms has further accentuated this tendency. Each of the publics – on the one hand amongst students and their families, and on the other hand amongst landlords – appears to be self-regarding, focused on its own context, without seeking to appreciate and accommodate the circumstances of the other, and without embracing some sort of reciprocity agreement or social pact that values mutual support. Similar arguments might apply to access to affordable housing more widely, for instance for seasonal workers in service or agricultural industries.

To attain an outcome centred on the interests of all publics, a set of nested institutions that enable and allow democratic deliberation throughout a territory’s economy and society would be required – Figure 3 depicts the necessary process. People must have opportunities safely to learn and experience, and to do so together. They need forums that enable them to observe, discuss, and share their understanding and ideas, as well as reflect critically on their own thinking and understanding, and that of others. They must be able to challenge themselves, and each other. They must be able to express their voice and, correspondingly, listen.[3] In turn, these requirements depend on the development of stimulating and supporting education and learning opportunities, as well as access to decision-making contexts where deliberative competences can be applied and refined in practice, through experience.

Inquiry, discussion, and sharing can enable people to increase their understanding, and reveal or change their awareness of the interests that they have in common in the consequences of a territory choosing particular aims and objectives. They can stimulate thinking and creativity, which might even catalyse the emergence of previously unimagined aims and objectives: “deliberation is a journey of exploration and discovery about preferences” (Sacchetti & Sugden, 2009).[4]

The implication is a change in paradigm. The organisation of production from a deliberative perspective needs to define competitiveness (and efficiency) in terms of its capacity to reduce the trade-offs between multiple aims. It needs to do so by defining rules which promote and require the inclusion of the interests of publics, specifying access to debate and decision-making beyond the usual criterion defined by property rights. It needs deliberative forums where instances and novel ideas can emerge.

Adopting this paradigm would imply a dynamic approach to innovation that changes the nature of production governance itself. Decisions on how to coordinate resources for competitiveness would generate different effects, for instance in terms of how income is distributed, contractual conditions for workers are defined, environmental, social and other forms of sustainability are conceived and pursued, and, more broadly, how the emergent interests of publics are accounted for.

Figure 3

The identification of publics and their interests

5.  For publics in practice

Bearing in mind that democratic deliberation is an ideal-type benchmark, in actual circumstance competitiveness might entail a territory successfully satisfying aims and objectives defined by compatibility with the interests of some publics. Each of those publics would need to identify themselves and their interests, for which forums to observe, inquire, share ideas, and learn – and in which people voice and listen – would be important. The territory would be characterised by a set of values and shared rules that support the emergence of publics, and the identification of their interests.

There would need to be awareness of the risk that the publics which are accounted for in practice might become an elite, excluding others. It might be necessary to emphasise the significance of shared rules such as rejecting attempts to control processes and outcomes, requiring inclusion of all people on equal terms, and being other-regarding, not only self-regarding. Publics would always need to be open to the emergence of new publics.

Variation in values and rules across territories might be associated with differences in economic context and technological trajectories, which might be linked to, for instance, the influence of secularisation, the mix of religions, or perhaps the prominence of particular elites in especially influential institutions or sectors.

Analogous to depiction of the organisation of production in Figure 1, observed territories could be mapped to a markets, hierarchies, publics triangle – Figure 4. The points of the triangle represent three ideal-types in which competitiveness is for aims and objectives defined by compatibility with, respectively, markets, or hierarchies, or the interests of publics. An area within the triangle represents observed competitiveness – what, in practice, competitiveness is for. As with Figure 2, the distance between that area and the point of the triangle representing compatibility with the interests of publics is a measure of the foregone public value generated by the observed economic system. Alternatively, it is a measure of the scope for improvement.

Mapping into the triangle can also reveal tensions and conflicts across and within markets, hierarchies, and the interests of publics. For instance, an emphasis on trade in free international markets might jeopardise the prospects of infant sectors being developed in a particular territory (because the more mature sectors in other territories might prevent others from entering the market), but possibly there is a public interest in those infant sectors being successful, for instance because they are central to the identity of the territory, how it sees itself and what it aspires to be. Or perhaps favouring large corporations in a particular sector would prevent small and medium sized enterprises from thriving, contrary to the interests of some publics, such as those sharing an interest in employment in the small and medium sized enterprises. To illustrate, in the territory of British Columbia (Canada), some might see the infant wine industry as important in this regard, and some might see the influence of large corporations in that industry as problematic (Pesme et al., 2022). Similar conflicting interests may occur between heterogeneous units (in terms of size) within the same conglomerate or group. There can also be conflicts across publics, and within the same public. For instance, the employees of a large corporation sharing interests in the consequences of its activities might be at odds with those sharing interests in employment in small and medium sized enterprises; and people within each of those publics might disagree with each other, for instance on the qualities of particular jobs.

Figure 4

Markets, hierarchies, publics, and the aims and objectives of a territory – mapping what competitiveness is for, i.e. its purpose

6.  Cooperation amongst researchers, community groups, citizens and policy-makers

The primary task of the university researcher is not to champion particular competitiveness policies. It is to study, stimulate inquiry, enable discussion, and challenge. With this in mind, what can researchers do to enhance processes of understanding and action in competitiveness policy in practice?

The framework suggested in this essay for addressing the nature and purposes of territorial competitiveness clearly points to areas where researchers might focus their attention. In principle, they are ideally placed to help to create forums to enable people to inquire, observe, discuss, share, reflect, challenge, learn, and experience, so that people might coalesce into publics, groups with identified and shared interests; and so that the translation of those interests into actions and policies might be stimulated and fostered.

Within universities and educational institutions, researchers might offer challenging and stimulating courses and programs that are grounded in inquiry, reflection, experience, etc., and intended to enable students to learn about processes for people to identify shared concerns. Researchers and students might also work with communities and industries, to enable practitioners and citizens.

To illustrate, consider two projects that were recently carried out in western Canada from the University of British Columbia.

First, a festival of social and economic change organised in the summer of 2022 in Kelowna, the principal city of the Okanagan region of British Columbia.[5] Through exhibitions, performances, and conversations, the festival explored social and economic change in real places: what it looks like, its effects, and how it is shaped. It brought together academics, artists, and members of publics, locally and from various parts of the world, in a forum where they could interact, express themselves, and inquire. One objective was to disrupt perhaps comfortable narratives associated with restricted, private interests.[6]

For instance, the exhibitions included art by Arleene Correa Valencia from a project entitled En Tiempos de Crisis.[7] The context for the work is the 2017 wildfires that swept through Northern California. It refers to the conditions in which migrant vineyard workers harvested grapes. In the artist’s own words: “While 254,000 acres scorched through the day and night, the air quality of Napa reached ‘hazardous’ – the level deemed most dangerous on the Environmental Protection Agency scale. These severe air quality conditions led a group of people to evacuate their homes in search of clean air. Others, like low-income agricultural workers, had no choice but to continue with the ongoing harvest in an attempt to save the area’s grapes. Tractors with heavy bright lights illuminated vineyards across the valley as people raced to pick grapes before the smoke could damage them. Agricultural workers worked through the night, exposing themselves to toxic air, risking their health and safety. These unseen heroes of our community are resilient embodiments of strength, commitment, and power.”[8] The exhibition in Kelowna could be seen as begging a question: do vineyard workers face similar conditions in the Okanagan, which is also a territory that produces wine and is prone to wildfires, and might there be publics with interests in such matters?

Second, an initiative between 2015 and 2019 that was supported and partly funded by the Canadian federal government to Position the British Columbia Wine Industry for International Growth.[9] In some respects, this initiative took an explicitly Deweyan approach to the interests of publics (Mooken et al., 2018; Pesme et al., 2022).

The funding supported a series of Wine Leaders Forums. They were organised and facilitated from the University of British Columbia, intended for industry participants, and focused on the strategic challenges of the British Columbia wine territory. The Forums aimed to “encourage collaboration and reflection. They enable participants to share a common interest in the consequences of actions, thus to see themselves as a public” (Pesme et al., 2022). This is illustrated by work on wine labelling. The context is that “accuracy about origin in labelling is crucial for a wine region to be taken seriously on an international level” (Sugden & Pesme, 2016). Wine industry participants at the 2015 Forum highlighted labelling as a strategic challenge – for them, it was crucial to the competitiveness of the British Columbia wine territory – but a difficult challenge to address without outside help. That was because of industry fragmentation: the large wine producers were often seen to have different interests to small and medium sized producers, and different parties sometimes found it hard to have fruitful discussions.

Following the 2015 Forum an industry task force on labelling was established. Like the Forums, it comprised industry participants, and was organised and facilitated from the University of British Columbia. “The task force committed to engage with industry stakeholders to provide recommendations about labelling and label architecture, including the specification of origin on labelling, for all wines that are produced by wineries in [British Columbia], both those containing 100% [British Columbia] grown grapes and others, for the purposes of growing international and domestic markets” (Sugden & Pesme, 2016). The task force findings were discussed at the 2016 Forum. As a consequence, winery representatives agreed to lobby for change to federal government labelling regulations. Forum participants were enabled “to consider themselves as part of a wider public with common interests in the consequences of regulatory requirements. The inclusive discussion empowered them to feel less marginalised within the industry, and they were able to voice their interest as a public” (Mooken et al., 2018).

Notwithstanding these experiences, the opportunities of researchers in practice to contribute to creating forums that support territorial competitiveness for the interests of publics should not be taken for granted. That is because university governance, and epistemic governance, typically crowd-out space for research and education focused on publics. Put another way, the organisation of modern universities in western economies typically confines them to an area close to the market-hierarchy spectrum in Figure 1.

Part of the difficulty is suggested by Martin Gurri’s stylised analysis of the relationship between universities, governments and businesses, and the consequences for publics. “An iron triangle of government, the universities, and the corporate world controls the careers of individual scientists. Consequently, the ideal of the lonely and disinterested seeker after truth has been superseded by that of the scientist-bureaucrat” (Gurri, 2018). Some people “believe that science is a tool of Big Business, that scientists are willing to poison us with genetically modified food and torture laboratory animals to earn a bigger profit for their paymasters. This may be an exaggeration, but, as a general proposition, it’s accurate enough” (Gurri, 2018). For others, “science has become the handmaiden of Big Government, raising climate and environmental scares to justify the imposition of ever more restrictive political controls over every aspect of life. And this, too, while overstating the case, is generally correct” (Gurri, 2018).

Consider also the rise and influence of university business and management schools that adopt and serve marketisation, and those schools being exemplar of university organisation (Sugden, 2019). They leave little room for the interests of publics.

Another concern is the approach of universities to epistemic governance. By analogy to the conceptualisation of the economic governance of organisations (discussed at the start of this essay), epistemic governance considers how decisions are made about what is accepted and valued as knowledge, ways of creating knowledge, and ways of using knowledge. Who makes the decisions, on what basis, for whose benefit? In the field of policy making, it has been argued that “epistemic governance speaks to and evokes actors’ deep-seated values and beliefs” (Alasuutari & Qadir, 2014). The same can hold for a university. Epistemic premises tend to be tacit and reproduced, not scrutinised. That can result in universities reinforcing extant centres of power. To illustrate, in the colonial construct that is the University of British Columbia,[10] epistemic governance seems to be inextricably entwined with nineteenth century British ways of organising universities. These include prizing western ways of doing and being, hence western approaches to knowledge, notwithstanding the university’s twenty first century commitments to truth and reconciliation in relationships with Indigenous people. Such practices tend to cut-off the free and open inquiry that might help to enable all publics to identify themselves and their interests.

These arguments do not mean that researchers have no opportunities to affect forums about competitiveness for publics. They suggest what typically or often occurs, and omit the less frequently observed possibilities that indicate spaces for researchers to be relevant to publics. It is the latter that researchers can build upon.

7.  Conclusion: what to do now

In principle, if territorial competitiveness is to be in the interests of publics, everybody associated with a territory has things to do in practice. But there is perhaps an onus on certain people to act first.

It would be immediately beneficial if policy-makers shifted their perspective. The dominant discourse on competitiveness currently favours narrow, private agendas, but policy-makers need not only think about competitiveness in terms of success in markets, or success for corporate business. They must also think of successfully achieving the aims and objectives of publics – groups of people who share interests in what is happening in the territory.

We have shown that there needs to be forums for democratic deliberation across all aspects of a territory’s economy and society. The forums must enable people to inquire, observe, discuss, and share their understanding and ideas, as well as reflect critically on their own thinking and understanding, and that of others. People have to be able to challenge themselves, and each other; to express their voice, and to listen. People can then appreciate where they have interests in common, what that means for the aims and objectives of a territory, and how it translates into actions and policies for territorial competitiveness.

None of this can happen by magic. It necessitates purposeful action to establish and nurture the forums. Policy-makers can play a decisive role in that messy yet essential process.

They would benefit from the active support of beneficiaries of the currently dominant discourse on competitiveness. Perhaps most especially, influential participants in business. As a minimum, current beneficiaries should not try to control forum processes and outcomes.

Step-by-step change is a practical goal. Everything cannot be done at once. Perhaps forums could be experimented with – piloted – around particular industries or communities where there is a willingness to act amongst a critical mass of policy-makers, business people, and citizens-.

Amongst those acting first there is also an onus on researchers. Their challenge is to open and nurture educational spaces that are relevant to publics. They might be able to develop courses and programs that are grounded in inquiry, reflection, experience, etc., and that enable students to learn about processes for people to identify shared concerns. They might be able to work with industries and communities, to enable practitioners and citizens.

In urging researchers to act, we suggest cooperation with people outside universities and educational institutions. For example, we have pointed to the opportunities in public festivals of social and economic change. In practice, the label “festival” has been applied to varied activities with wide ranging purposes. Some are intended to be integral to market economic success and development, i.e., to production that is organised primarily through markets and/or market-focused hierarchies (Edensor & Sumartojo, 2018). We have something else in mind: festivals centred on publics and their interests; that enable inquiry, observing, sharing, learning, voicing and listening; that are underpinned by particular values and rules, including that participants reject attempts to control, require inclusion, and are other-regarding. To achieve this outcome, festivals might be created and developed by cooperation between researchers and people interested in a territory: citizens, community groups, policy-makers, business people, and perhaps diaspora from the territory living elsewhere, yet maintaining ongoing, shared concerns.

This would enable researchers to bring to bear their capabilities to study, stimulate inquiry, enable discussion, and challenge. It would enable them to work with people from diverse walks of life, with varied understandings, experiences, and histories, all bringing their own capabilities, and with everyone linked through a shared willingness to engage in the interests of publics. By cooperating, people might impact territorial competitiveness in practice.

References

Alasuutari, P., & Qadir, A. (2014). Epistemic governance: An approach to the politics of policy-making. European Journal of Cultural and Political Sociology, 1(1), 67-84. https://doi.org/10.1080/23254823.2014.887986

Branston, J.R., Cowling, K., & Sugden, R. (2006a). Corporate governance and the public interest. International Review of Applied Economics, 20(2), 189-212. https://doi.org/10.1080/02692170600581110

Branston, J.R., Rubini, L., Sugden, R., & Wilson, J.R. (2006b). The healthy development of economies: A strategic framework for competitiveness in the health industry. Review of Social Economy, 64(3), 301-329. https://doi.org/10.1080/00346760600892717

Branston, J.R., Cowling, K.G., & Tomlinson, P.R. (2016). Addressing ‘strategic failure’: Widening the public interest in the UK financial and energy sectors. In Begley, J., Coffey, D., Donnelly, T., & Thornley, C. (Eds.), Global economic crisis and local economic development (pp. 198–222). Routledge.

Bristow, G. (2005). Everyone’s a ‘winner’: Problematising the discourse of regional competitiveness. Journal of Economic Geography, 5(3), 285–305. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/lbh063

Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x

Conyon, M., Ellman, M., Pitelis, C.N., Shipman, A., & Tomlinson, P.R. (2022). Big tech oligopolies, Keith Cowling, and monopoly capitalism. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 46, 1205–1224. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/beac062

Dewey, J. (1927). The public and its problems: An essay in political inquiry. Holt. Ohio University Press.

Edensor, T., & Sumartojo, S. (2018). Reconfiguring familiar worlds with light projection: The Gertrude Street Projection Festival, 2017. GeoHumanities, 4(1), 112-131. https://doi.org/10.1080/2373566X.2018.1446760

Gurri, M. (2018). The revolt of the public and the crisis of authority in the new millennium. Stripe Press.

Hirschman, A.O. (1970). Exit, voice, and loyalty: Responses to decline in firms, organizations and states. Harvard University Press.

Marglin, S.A. (1974). What do bosses Do? The origins and functions of hierarchy in capitalist production. Review of Radical Political Economics,6(2), 60–112. https://doi.org/10.1177/048661347400600206

Mooken, M., Sugden, R., & Valania, M. (2018). University impact on the development of industries in peripheral regions: Knowledge organization and the British Columbia wine industry. BC Studies: The British Columbian Quarterly, 198 (Summer), 125-152. https://doi.org/10.14288/bcs.v0i198.189278

Pesme, J.O., Sugden, R., Mooken, M., Valania, M., & Buschert, K. (2022). A reflective process to explore identity in an emerging wine territory: The example of British Columbia. International Journal of Wine Business Research, 34(1), 1-18. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/IJWBR-07-2020-0034

Sacchetti, S. (2015). Inclusive and exclusive social preferences: A Deweyan framework to explain governance heterogeneity. Journal of Business Ethics, 126, 473-485. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1971-0

Sacchetti, S., & Borzaga, C. (2021). The foundations of the “public organisation”: Governance failure and the problem of external effects. Journal of Management and Governance, 25, 731-758. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10997-020-09525-x

Sacchetti, S., & Sugden, R. (2009a). The organization of production and its publics: Mental proximity, markets and hierarchies. Review of Social Economy, 67(3), 289-311. https://doi.org/10.1080/00346760802621906

Sacchetti, S., & Sugden, R. (2009b). Positioning order, disorder and creativity in research choices on local development. In Sacchetti S. & Sugden, R. (Eds.), Knowledge in the development of economies. Institutional choices under globalisation (pp. 269-288). Edward Elgar. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781849802345

Sacchetti, F., Sacchetti, S., & Sugden, R. (2009). Creativity and socio-economic development: Space for the interests of publics. International Review of Applied Economics, 23(6), 653-672. https://doi.org/10.1080/02692170903239846

Sugden, R. (2019). Management education in a public university in the economic periphery: Reflections in action on UBC in Interior British Columbia. Journal of Entrepreneurial and Organizational Diversity, 8(2), 1-26. http://dx.doi.org/10.5947/jeod.2019.006

Sugden, R., & Pesme, J.O. (2016). Final report and recommendations of the task force on labelling and presentation. University of British Columbia Library. https://open.library.ubc.ca/soa/cIRcle/collections/facultyresearchandpublications/52383/items/1.0395428?o=0

Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. Macmillan.


[*] PhD Commerce, Industrial Economic Policy from the University of Birmingham, (UK). He is Professor in Political Economy at the Department of Sociology and Social Research, at the University of Trento (Italy). Co-Chief Editor of the Journal of Entrepreneurial and Organizational Diversity and member of EMES and the European Research Board of the International Cooperative Alliance.

[**] PhD in Economics from the University of Warwick (UK). He is currently Professor at the Okanagan campus of the University of British Columbia (Canada), in Syilx Okanagan Nation territory. His research focuses on economic organisation, governance, the interests of publics, and the socio-economic development of territories.

More information about the authors at the end of this article.

The authors would like to thank Keith Sugden and Marcela Valania for discussion, and the journal editors and referees for comments. Silvia Sacchetti acknowledges EU funding NextGenerationEU – Project ECS000043 – Innovation Ecosystem Program “Interconnected Northeast Innovation Ecosystem (iNEST),” CUP H43C22000540006 and – Next Generation EU, PRIN 2022, project “sMArT cities CHAllenges and opportunities: a participatory approach to the design of sustainable, creative and connected cities (MATCHA)” (2022ZCM5MY) – CUP E53D23010490006.

[1] A total cost model that considers the overall efficiency by including the net costs of excluding publics from the governance of the corporation, is suggested in Sacchetti and Borzaga (2021).

[2] This conception aligns with the suggestions about competitiveness in the health industry in Branston et al. (2006b).

[3] On voice, see Hirschman (1970).

[4] On creativity, see Sacchetti et al. (2009).

[5] The university researchers involved in coordinating the festival were Malida Mooken, Roger Sugden, and Marcela Valania.

[6] An earlier initiative in a related spirit is the 2007 Festival on Creativity and Economic Development, organised in and around Gambettola, Italy, by Silvia Sacchetti, Roger Sugden and Marcela Valania, in cooperation with municipalities and other territorial actors. Sacchetti is from Gambettola, and Sacchetti, Sugden and Valania were then based at the University of Birmingham, England. The festival brought together artists, citizens, and academics to seize opportunities for critical thinking, and to shape ideas and perspectives (Sacchetti & Sugden, 2009b).

[8] As reproduced in the festival brochure: https://issuu.com/sechange/docs/se-changefestivalfinal (accessed 6th May 2024)

[9] The project coordinating group comprised Kim Buschert, Malida Mooken, Jacques-Olivier Pesme, Roger Sugden, and Marcela Valania.

About the authors

SILVIA SACCHETTI. PhD Commerce, Industrial Economic Policy (University of Birmingham, UK) is Professor in Political Economy at the Department of Sociology and Social Research, at the University of Trento (Italy). Before she has covered roles in the UK, at the University of Birmingham, University of Stirling, and The Open University. She collaborates with EURICSE, the European Research Institute on Cooperatives and Social Enterprise, with special focus on firm governance and human development processes that include publics, their motivational diversity, creativity, and production of public value. Current applications are in work-integration, educational, and cultural sectors. She acts as Co-Chief Editor of the Journal of Entrepreneurial and Organizational Diversity. She is a member of EMES and the European Research Board of the International Cooperative Alliance. Her email is silvia.sacchetti@unitn.it https://orcid.org/0000-0002-5662-2074

Doctora en Comercio, Política Económica Industrial (Universidad de Birmingham, Reino Unido), es Profesora de Economía Política en el Departamento de Sociología e Investigación Social de la Universidad de Trento (Italia). Anteriormente ha ocupado cargos en el Reino Unido, en la Universidad de Birmingham, la Universidad de Stirling y The Open University. Colabora con EURICSE, el Instituto Europeo de Investigación en Cooperativas y Empresas Sociales, con un enfoque especial en la gobernanza de empresas y los procesos de desarrollo humano que incluyen a los públicos, su diversidad motivacional, creatividad y producción de valor público. Las aplicaciones actuales de su trabajo están en los sectores de integración laboral, educación y cultura. Es coeditora jefe del Journal of Entrepreneurial and Organizational Diversity. Es miembro de EMES y del Consejo de Investigación Europeo de la Alianza Cooperativa Internacional. Su correo electrónico es silvia.sacchetti@unitn.it https://orcid.org/0000-0002-5662-2074

ROGER SUGDEN. PhD in Economics from the University of Warwick (UK). He is currently Professor at the Okanagan campus of the University of British Columbia (Canada), in Syilx Okanagan Nation territory. He has previously worked at the University of Stirling (Scotland), University of Birmingham (England), University of Edinburgh (Scotland), and the Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung (Germany). He has been Visiting Scholar at the University of Cambridge (England), and Visiting Professor at the Università degli Studi di Ferrara (Italy). His research focuses on economic organisation, governance, the interests of publics, and the socio-economic development of territories. His email is roger.sugden@ubc.ca

Doctor en Economía por la Universidad de Warwick (Reino Unido). Actualmente es Profesor en el campus de Okanagan de la Universidad de Columbia Británica (Canadá), en el territorio de la Nación Syilx Okanagan. Anteriormente ha trabajado en la Universidad de Stirling (Escocia), la Universidad de Birmingham (Inglaterra), la Universidad de Edimburgo (Escocia) y el Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung (Alemania). Ha sido Investigador Visitante en la Universidad de Cambridge (Inglaterra) y Profesor Visitante en la Università degli Studi di Ferrara (Italia). Su investigación se centra en la organización económica, la gobernanza, los intereses de los públicos y el desarrollo socioeconómico de los territorios. Su correo electrónico es roger.sugden@ubc.ca https://orcid.org/0009-0009-7505-3071

 

Acceso Abierto, Copias Impresas y Derechos de Autoría

El Boletín de Estudios Económicos es una revista de acceso abierto, lo que significa que todo el contenido está disponible gratuitamente para los usuarios y sus instituciones. Los usuarios pueden leer, descargar, copiar, distribuir, imprimir, buscar o enlazar los textos completos de los artículos, o utilizarlos para cualquier otro fin lícito, sin pedir permiso previo a la Editorial o al autor; siempre que se cite adecuadamente el trabajo original y se indique claramente cualquier modificación del mismo. Esto se ajusta a la definición de acceso abierto de la OAI.

Se pueden proporcionar copias impresas de la revista si se solicita. Se trata de copias en color, impresas y acabadas profesionalmente. Las copias impresas tienen un coste. Para pedir una copia impresa de un artículo o de un número, envíe un correo electrónico al editor de producción con su solicitud (<beejournal@deusto.es>).

Cuando los autores envían un artículo para su revisión y publicación en el Boletín de Estudios Económicos, conservan sus derechos de autor, pero aceptan automáticamente conceder los derechos de publicación no exclusivos a la Editorial (del Boletín de Estudios Económicos) y aceptan que el artículo se publique bajo una licencia Creative Commons, si el artículo es aceptado para su publicación. Se recomienda a los autores que lean atentamente sus derechos. Creemos que este enfoque garantiza un acuerdo justo para ambas partes. La licencia concedida permite a la Editorial editar y maquetar el artículo, que se incluirá en un próximo número y se distribuirá en cualquier medio online y offline que la Editorial considere necesario para promocionar el artículo, los autores y la revista. Este párrafo se incluye en las Directrices para los autores.

Para más información sobre la licencia Creative Commons, visite: https://creativecommons.org.

Open Access, Hard Copies and Copyright

The Bulletin of Economic Studies is an Open Access journal which means that all its content is available free of charge to users and their institutions. Users are allowed to read, download, copy, distribute, print, search, or link to the full texts of the articles, or use them for any other lawful purpose, without asking prior permission from the publisher or the author; provided the original work is properly cited and any changes to the original are clearly indicated. This is in accordance with the OAI definition of Open Access.

Hard copies of the journal can be provided upon request. These are colour copies, professionally printed and finished. Hard copies incur a fee. To order a hard copy of an article or an issue, please email the production editor with your request (<beejournal@deusto.es>).

When authors submit a paper for reviewing and publishing, they retain their copyright, but they automatically agree to grant non-exclusive publishing rights to the Publisher and agree that the paper will be published under a Creative Commons licence, if the paper is accepted for publication. Authors are encouraged to read their rights carefully. We believe this approach ensures a fair arrangement for both parties. The licence granted allows the Publisher to edit and typeset the paper, which will be included in a forthcoming issue and distributed in any online and offline medium that the journal deems necessary in order to promote the paper, the authors, and the Journal. This paragraph is included in the Guidelines for Authors.

For more information about the Creative Commons Licence, please visit: https://creativecommons.org.